Center for Business and Economic Research - Ball State University


CBER Data Center
Projects and PublicationsEconomic IndicatorsWeekly CommentaryCommunity Asset InventoryManufacturing Scorecard

About

Commentaries are published weekly and distributed through the Indianapolis Business Journal and many other print and online publications. Disclaimer

RSS Feed

Disclaimer

The views expressed in these commentaries do not reflect those of Ball State University or the Center for Business and Economic Research.

Recent

Previewing the Long-Term Effects of TariffsThe dominant effect of the Trump tariffs will be to raise production costs on almost every American manufacturing firm.

It’s TDS to Suppose These Tariffs Are WorkingTrump has pushed the U.S. into an economic downturn that will be especially hurtful to Hoosiers.

Trump’s Tariff Recession Is HereMy new forecast, completed in late April, predicts a national recession began as early as March in reaction to Trump’s tarriffs.

Two Key Economic Lessons in One BillHoosiers face trade-offs and opportunity costs in the wake of SEA1.

View archives

Top Tags

jobs and employment 262
economics 203
state and local government 188
education 186
indiana 173
economic development 171
taxes 146
budget and spending 145
law and public policy 144
workforce and human capital 139
Browse all tags
Reporter / Admin Login

March 23, 2014

Inflation and Growth

Folks who write about research for a popular audience naturally tend to simplify some of the elements. This is not “dumbing down” the discussion, but rather it is allowing someone without technical training in a given area to understand just what those with that training are thinking. For example, when your physician gives you a helpful tip on wellness, she doesn’t dig into cell biology. Still, there’s always a danger in this, and one of the worst pitfalls in economics is how we think about economic growth and government stimulus.

In most AP high school or introductory college economics classes, we learn about something called gross domestic product. We learn that this GDP is the sum of consumer spending, investment by businesses, government spending, and the net trade balance (exports minus imports). This is true enough, and it sets up the next lesson, which is a basic model of the overall, or macroeconomy. In this very simple model, GDP gets larger if there is an increase in consumption, investment, government spending, or the net trade balance.

This model is a superb way to teach the fundamentals of model building to students, so it is a great didactic tool. It can also be comforting because, like all models, it abstracts difficult ideas into digestible little pieces. If our economic education stopped there, we’d have a nice, neat, easily understood model of the economy with which to go about understanding the world. There’s just one little problem; no economists have ever used this model to explain economic growth.

A very long time ago, economists used this approach to model how a sudden drop in investment or consumption could be remedied by government stimulus. An astute reader should recognize this as the Keynesian explanation for the New Deal. But economists never, ever used this to explain long-term growth. What is more, economists long ago rejected this model as a way to explain how stimulus might work to pull an economy out of recession.

These assertions might prompt the question: Why is it that economics rejected such a model? Well, it is not that it is too simple; simple is good. Nor is it due to fashion; this remains a fashionable model among policymakers who are innocent of economics. The reason economists rejected this model is the plain, old-fashioned scientific method. Over and over, and over again, efforts to test the model against real data proved it false. So, it was rejected and replaced by a model that has survived nearly a half century of empirical challenges.

The new model, not coincidently named the new Keynesian model, suggests that a government stimulus might work to temporarily boost consumption or investment just like the old Keynesian model does. But, a very different mechanism is at work. The new model requires businesses and households to adjust their buying because of fears of expected inflation.

Applying current public policy and government spending, the new model shows that the federal government is pursuing inflation as a gateway to economic recovery. If the new model is right, we will have to face inflation before we see real recovery.­

Link to this commentary: https://commentaries.cberdata.org/726/inflation-and-growth

Tags: economic theory, prices and inflation, growth


About the Author

Michael Hicks cberdirector@bsu.edu

Michael J. Hicks, PhD, is the director of the Center for Business and Economic Research and the George and Frances Ball distinguished professor of economics in the Miller College of Business at Ball State University. Note: The views expressed here are solely those of the author, and do not represent those of funders, associations, any entity of Ball State University, or its governing body.

© Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University

About Ball State CBER Data Center

Ball State CBER Data Center is one-stop shop for economic data including demographics, education, health, and social capital. Our easy-to-use, visual web tools offer data collection and analysis for grant writers, economic developers, policy makers, and the general public.

Ball State CBER Data Center (cberdata.org) is a product of the Center for Business and Economic Research at Ball State University. CBER's mission is to conduct relevant and timely public policy research on a wide range of economic issues affecting the state and nation. Learn more.

Terms of Service

Center for Business and Economic Research

Ball State University • Whitinger Business Building, room 149
2000 W. University Ave.
Muncie, IN 47306-0360
Phone:
765-285-5926
Email:
cber@bsu.edu
Website:
www.bsu.edu/cber
Facebook:
www.facebook.com/BallStateCBER
Twitter:
www.twitter.com/BallStateCBER
Close