Center for Business and Economic Research - Ball State University


CBER Data Center
Projects and PublicationsEconomic IndicatorsWeekly CommentaryCommunity Asset InventoryManufacturing Scorecard

About

Commentaries are published weekly and distributed through the Indianapolis Business Journal and many other print and online publications. Disclaimer

RSS Feed

Disclaimer

The views expressed in these commentaries do not reflect those of Ball State University or the Center for Business and Economic Research.

Recent

The 2023 ForecastThe reason for worry about a recession is the Federal Reserve’s response to high inflation.

Some Labor Market Facts You Won’t Read ElsewhereIndiana is simply not producing a 21st century workforce.

Three Types of Public DebtAll types of public debt are effectively transfers of wealth from the future to our present selves.

Remote Work Is Indiana’s Biggest Opportunity and RiskThere are now more Hoosiers in remote work than there are in manufacturing and logistics combined.

View archives

Top Tags

jobs and employment 225
economics 173
education 144
economic development 141
taxes 122
state and local government 119
finance 107
recession 100
budget and spending 98
indiana 96
Browse all tags
Reporter / Admin Login

December 20, 2010

The What and When of Inflation

It is almost impossible to turn on a radio, read a blog, or thumb through newspaper business pages without a strong forewarning of inflation.  In this column I have worried about inflation as far back as mid-2009.  Since then inflation has been very tame.  Some have even worried about the specter of deflation – a far more troubling phenomenon that has likewise been absent.  It may be worth explaining how all this works.

All economists know that, at its core, inflation is solely caused by too much money chasing too few goods.  But unless you’ve been steeled to think of the world in terms of simultaneous equations, this is a pretty abstract notion.  Let me use an easier example:

Suppose there were two villages that made goods and traded them with each other, each using its own distinct currency.  Initially, the value of each village’s currency is identical, but one day, the monetary authority in one village decided to print a great deal of money and distribute it to citizens. At first, the villagers with the new cash would be pleased to spend the money in the other village, but it wouldn’t take long until the denizens of the second village got wise and raised the price of their goods in terms of the first village’s currency.  Saddened, the holders of the devalued money would return home to buy goods – but there also, merchants would sense the extra demand for their goods and raise prices.  This is inflation.

 Please don’t think this example is meant to be condescending.  It is actually a fine model for both exchange rate variability and inflation and something like this is the basis for many more sophisticated models.  But as long as you understand that concept, it is what is absent from the example that is really fascinating.

Suppose the printing of money in the first village was done to compensate for a terrible drought’s effect on harvest.  The idea was to cause some villagers in both locations to produce more goods to fill the gap in demand.  This would work to some degree, but certainly not in the long run, and only as long as workers make more goods instead of simply raising prices.  The extra money would also reduce the costs of borrowing money (there is more in supply) so could boost demand for capital goods (like irrigation ditches) – so far, so good.  The problem arises as villagers can no longer produce more goods to fill the gap and instead raise prices. 

In the U.S., and to a lesser extent elsewhere, we’ve increased the money supply significantly, and it looks like it is boosting demand, rather than causing prices to rise.  The depth of the recession has lessened the ability of firms to raise prices. As the economy recovers, this will end – prices will rise and we will have inflation.  Experience tells us that while inflation may be delayed once it starts, it is apt to accelerate dangerously. When and how much are matters of great supposing.

Link to this commentary: https://commentaries.cberdata.org/544/the-what-and-when-of-inflation

Tags: prices and inflation, recession


About the Author

Michael Hicks cberdirector@bsu.edu

Michael J. Hicks, PhD, is the director of the Center for Business and Economic Research and the George and Frances Ball distinguished professor of economics in the Miller College of Business at Ball State University. Hicks earned doctoral and master’s degrees in economics from the University of Tennessee and a bachelor’s degree in economics from Virginia Military Institute. He has authored two books and more than 60 scholarly works focusing on state and local public policy, including tax and expenditure policy and the impact of Wal-Mart on local economies.

© Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University

About Ball State CBER Data Center

Ball State CBER Data Center is one-stop shop for economic data including demographics, education, health, and social capital. Our easy-to-use, visual web tools offer data collection and analysis for grant writers, economic developers, policy makers, and the general public.

Ball State CBER Data Center (cberdata.org) is a product of the Center for Business and Economic Research at Ball State University. CBER's mission is to conduct relevant and timely public policy research on a wide range of economic issues affecting the state and nation. Learn more.

Terms of Service

Center for Business and Economic Research

Ball State University • Whitinger Business Building, room 149
2000 W. University Ave.
Muncie, IN 47306-0360
Phone:
765-285-5926
Email:
cber@bsu.edu
Website:
www.bsu.edu/cber
Facebook:
www.facebook.com/BallStateCBER
Twitter:
www.twitter.com/BallStateCBER
Close