Center for Business and Economic Research - Ball State University


CBER Data Center
Projects and PublicationsEconomic IndicatorsWeekly CommentaryCommunity Asset InventoryManufacturing Scorecard

About

Commentaries are published weekly and distributed through the Indianapolis Business Journal and many other print and online publications. Disclaimer

RSS Feed

Disclaimer

The views expressed in these commentaries do not reflect those of Ball State University or the Center for Business and Economic Research.

Recent

Two Key Economic Lessons in One BillHoosiers face trade-offs and opportunity costs in the wake of SEA1.

Time to Fix Economic Development PolicyAllocating tax dollars to land development won’t cause economic growth.

The Unanticipated Effects of SB1Businesses, governments and households may all feel the effects.

The Stupidest of PoliciesThis whipsawing of tariff rates has unnerved financial markets, which on Wednesday, were toying with a liquidity crisis.

View archives

Top Tags

jobs and employment 261
economics 201
state and local government 188
education 186
economic development 171
indiana 171
budget and spending 145
taxes 144
law and public policy 142
workforce and human capital 139
Browse all tags
Reporter / Admin Login

November 3, 2019

Monopsony Problems Get Hearing in Congress

Amid all the other kerfuffle this week, Congress held hearings on growing evidence of monopsony power in labor markets. For those lucky few who didn’t take a labor economics course, monopsony is simply the ability of a few large local employers to control local labor markets. The worry is simply that monopsony causes wages to be lower and grow more sluggishly than they would in competitive markets. The hearing featured a host of young researchers whose work is unlocking growing evidence of this problem.

This growing focus on monopsony power in local labor markets comes at a time of similarly increased scrutiny of monopoly power in technology and healthcare companies. Nationwide, enforcement of laws designed to prevent monopoly power suffered a lengthy dry spell, and it is likely that much of the growth of both problems are connected by individual firms. Across much of the nation, we see firms exercising more power both in markets for goods or services as well as markets for workers.

Before complimenting this work and policy question, I have a few caveats. First, measuring market power in occupations is harder than it seems. Within the commuting zone where I work and live, there are a dozen and a half economists who all employed by the same establishment. We are a highly concentrated occupation, but in truth, a job announcement for an economist will bring applications from five continents. This is one example only, but clearly some of the most concentrated occupations are likely to draw employees from broad markets.

A second note is that monopsony power is not simply a measure of ‘bigness.’ Walmart is often the largest employer in a state or county, but two decades of research finds no convincing evidence of monopsony problems. Trust me, I spent a big part of three years looking for it without success. Monopsony power occurs when a few employers control wages and work conditions within reasonable commuting distances.

Some of the best work on monopsony comes from Jose Azar, Ioana Marinescu and Marshall Steinbaum. They examined data on job openings in commuter zones from the commercial site CareerBuilder.com. They report significant market concentration of job openings, a prime measure of monopsony. They also found that for the same occupation, wages dropped as markets became more concentrated. This careful work changed my mind about the problem.

The good news is that in their map of concentration, Indiana fared pretty well. Unsurprisingly, the places which did worse than Indiana had distant rural counties. Indiana has lots of rural places, but we are a compact state. More than 85 percent of Hoosiers live within a short drive from an urban area, so job location choices are relatively good here. The bad news is that for many occupations, nearly every commuting zone in the nation is concentrated, so doing relatively well is poor consolation. Still, the most interesting result from research on monopsony power is not merely the negative wage effect, but two other warning signs.

First, monopsony power may be a leading contributor to urbanization. Large urban labor markets are less concentrated, so workers will find them more attractive. Over the past two decades, the rate of urbanization has accelerated, causing significant population decline in rural, small towns and medium-sized cities. This problem is long past the critical stage in Indiana, with only a few counties experiencing meaningful population growth in this century.

Second, monopsony power can lead to the perception of labor shortages. Naturally, firms operating in monopsony markets will wish to hire a nearly endless supply of workers. After all, wages are beneath the competitive level. But, as I must often remind policymakers, workers also get a choice. Wages below the competitive level will attract only those workers without the ability to relocate. Thus, firms mistake the presence of monopsony power for a labor shortage. Indeed, several technical studies identify complaints of ‘reported vacancies’ without growing wages is strong evidence of monopsony power.

In the end, the level of monopsony power is an empirical question. Economists should be spending more time and energy expanding analysis of these issues. As that occurs, we can also think through policies that limit the expansion of monopsony markets. For example, the research center I direct no longer conducts occupational wage surveys. In my judgement, these were used too often to suppress wages. I took this action before the Federal Trade Commission warned human resource officials about the practice in 2016.

The congressional testimony argued for a broad expansion of anti-trust enforcement. This follows that important 2016 FTC warning listing civil enforcement against hospitals, technology companies and trade associations for violating laws designed to ensure competitive labor markets. So, it seems likely that both state and federal governments will begin more earnest review of their anti-trust enforcement. That will be good for workers, for communities that suffer through monopsony and for firms that pay competitive wage rates.

Link to this commentary: https://commentaries.cberdata.org/1028/monopsony-problems-get-hearing-in-congress

Tags: monopoly, jobs and employment, income and wages, business


About the Author

Michael Hicks cberdirector@bsu.edu

Michael J. Hicks, PhD, is the director of the Center for Business and Economic Research and the George and Frances Ball distinguished professor of economics in the Miller College of Business at Ball State University. Note: The views expressed here are solely those of the author, and do not represent those of funders, associations, any entity of Ball State University, or its governing body.

© Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University

About Ball State CBER Data Center

Ball State CBER Data Center is one-stop shop for economic data including demographics, education, health, and social capital. Our easy-to-use, visual web tools offer data collection and analysis for grant writers, economic developers, policy makers, and the general public.

Ball State CBER Data Center (cberdata.org) is a product of the Center for Business and Economic Research at Ball State University. CBER's mission is to conduct relevant and timely public policy research on a wide range of economic issues affecting the state and nation. Learn more.

Terms of Service

Center for Business and Economic Research

Ball State University • Whitinger Business Building, room 149
2000 W. University Ave.
Muncie, IN 47306-0360
Phone:
765-285-5926
Email:
cber@bsu.edu
Website:
www.bsu.edu/cber
Facebook:
www.facebook.com/BallStateCBER
Twitter:
www.twitter.com/BallStateCBER
Close