Center for Business and Economic Research - Ball State University


CBER Data Center
Projects and PublicationsEconomic IndicatorsWeekly CommentaryCommunity Asset InventoryManufacturing Scorecard

About

Commentaries are published weekly and distributed through the Indianapolis Business Journal and many other print and online publications. Disclaimer

RSS Feed

Disclaimer

The views expressed in these commentaries do not reflect those of Ball State University or the Center for Business and Economic Research.

Recent

Bank Failures Warn of Deeper Economic ProblemsDuring the Great Recession, a whopping 0.014 percent of banks were closed by the FDIC.

Remote Work Through the Eyes of Three 20-SomethingsRemote work is here to stay.

Remote Work and Labor MarketsThere are more remote workers today than there are immigrants in the U.S.

The Amish in IndianaIt is hard not to draw similarities between the Amish and newer immigrant groups.

View archives

Top Tags

jobs and employment 228
economics 176
education 146
economic development 144
state and local government 124
taxes 122
finance 108
budget and spending 100
recession 100
indiana 99
Browse all tags
Reporter / Admin Login

February 10, 2019

Monopoly Isn’t Just a Game Anymore

Monopoly is again becoming interesting, and I don’t mean the board game. Over the past few years, both academic and policy researchers have found growing evidence of market concentration or lack of competition in many business sectors. For a variety of reasons, this will likely emerge as a campaign issue in the next national election, so it is helpful to understand what economists mean when they talk about competition. 

Economists favor competitive markets over monopoly-like markets because competition yields much better outcomes to both consumers and producers. However, this remains a hard concept for many to grasp. It’s likely that every understands that competition yields lower prices, higher levels of production and, over the long run, more innovation. It also yields more efficient use of inputs such as land, talent and capital. Competitive firms also adjust more quickly to consumer demand, supplying everything from water or gasoline in a natural disaster to high-end consumer goods in the place and time people want to buy them. 

Markets don’t always work perfectly, which is what this column is ultimately about. But, when they work well, no other human contrivance is as effective at matching desires to goods and services and workers to the jobs they want. What often confuses folks about competitive markets is that individual firms don’t want to be in a competitive market. 

For individual businesses, it is better to avoid competition and operate in markets with few rivals. Individual businesses go to great lengths to deter rivals, secure some capacity to set price and protect themselves from competition. However, firms in competition hire more workers and produce more goods than those who can protect themselves from competition. So, it is better for commerce as a whole to operate in competitive markets. That part slips by many people who view the economy as simply the aggregate experience of a bunch of individual firms, which it is not.

The United States has long led the world in policies designed to protect against monopolies. The Sherman Act of 1890 outlawed direct collusion between firms. Since then, the US has developed a streamlined and economically informed set of laws and legal precedent that promote competition. We just have not used them as much as we might. 

Over the past 25 years or so, competition in the US has dwindled. New firm creation has plummeted and the share of employment in the largest few firms in each industry has grown significantly. This is known as market concentration and is a big signal of growing monopolization. 

The biggest concern over market concentration has long been its effect on the price and availability of goods and services. Monopolies and monopoly-like market conditions are among the few places where the bulk of economists believe warrant market intervention. Indeed, almost the only disagreement about the scale and scope of government intervention comes in our ability to judge effectively when a market possesses too little competition.

For example, in many cases monopolies are transient. Facebook, for example, developed very deep market concentration in social media. However, if my teenagers are to be believed, Facebook is now nothing more than a reliquary of childhood vacation pictures accessed mainly by an ancient race of people aged 40 and older. This is not a recipe for sustained monopoly, so natural market forces alone may be as effective as government in promoting competition in this market. 

More recently, there is growing evidence that less competitive markets are influencing more than just prices, and may now play a role in suppressing wage growth. In rural places and small towns, this has likely been the case for some time, but several recent studies suggest the problem is broader than has long been thought to be the case. 

Right now, there is growing evidence that lack of competition in labor markets is a broad problem. Still, this is an area where politicians on both the right and left are likely to see policy concerns. If so, state policies towards business should be among the first to see pressure for reforms. I see two major policy concerns.

First, state policies that funnel workers into specific occupations will face much more scrutiny than they currently do. These policies likely restrict wage growth while overwhelmingly benefitting just a few larger firms. Because these policies face almost no oversight today, this would be an easy problem to address. Second, there is likely to be a growing discomfort with tax incentives. Large businesses are disproportionate beneficiaries of tax incentives, which is ironic since larger firms already benefit from low-capital costs in ways small firms cannot. 

As with many state policies, special advantages given to large firms often come at the expense of their smaller, less well-connected competitors. Worse still, neither workers nor taxpayers seem to benefit much from these policies. So, in a world where small firms are a shrinking share of the economy and wage growth is sluggish, there should be growing call for change. That change should probably start here.

Link to this commentary: https://commentaries.cberdata.org/989/monopoly-isn-t-just-a-game-anymore

Tags: business, regulation


About the Author

Michael Hicks cberdirector@bsu.edu

Michael J. Hicks, PhD, is the director of the Center for Business and Economic Research and the George and Frances Ball distinguished professor of economics in the Miller College of Business at Ball State University. Hicks earned doctoral and master’s degrees in economics from the University of Tennessee and a bachelor’s degree in economics from Virginia Military Institute. He has authored two books and more than 60 scholarly works focusing on state and local public policy, including tax and expenditure policy and the impact of Wal-Mart on local economies.

© Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University

About Ball State CBER Data Center

Ball State CBER Data Center is one-stop shop for economic data including demographics, education, health, and social capital. Our easy-to-use, visual web tools offer data collection and analysis for grant writers, economic developers, policy makers, and the general public.

Ball State CBER Data Center (cberdata.org) is a product of the Center for Business and Economic Research at Ball State University. CBER's mission is to conduct relevant and timely public policy research on a wide range of economic issues affecting the state and nation. Learn more.

Terms of Service

Center for Business and Economic Research

Ball State University • Whitinger Business Building, room 149
2000 W. University Ave.
Muncie, IN 47306-0360
Phone:
765-285-5926
Email:
cber@bsu.edu
Website:
www.bsu.edu/cber
Facebook:
www.facebook.com/BallStateCBER
Twitter:
www.twitter.com/BallStateCBER
Close